De Minimis
  • Home
  • Podcast
  • Art
  • Get published!
  • ABOUT US
  • Archive
    • 2018
    • 2017
    • 2017 >
      • Semester 2 (Volume 12) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8 (election issue)
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
        • Issue 12
    • 2016 >
      • Semester 1 (Volume 9) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
        • Issue 12
      • Semester 2 (Volume 10) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8 (Election Issue)
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
        • Issue 12
        • Issue 13 (test)
    • 2015 >
      • Semester 1 (Volume 7) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
      • Semester 2 (Volume 8) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
    • 2014 >
      • Semester 1 (Volume 5) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
      • Semester 2 (Volume 6) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 12
    • 2013 >
      • Issue 1
      • Issue 2
      • Issue 3
      • Issue 4
      • Issue 5
      • Issue 6
    • 2012 >
      • Semester 1 (Volume 1) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
        • Issue 12
      • Semester 2 (Volume 2) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
        • Issue 12

Melbourne Law School Fees Rising at Double the Rate of Inflation

10/10/2016

 
DUNCAN WALLACE
Volume 10, Issue 11
A student contacted me last week to express the horror they felt when they looked at their statement of liability. Since 2014, the year they started the JD, fees for each subject (or ‘unit’) had gone up by $368. This meant that, compared to 2014, they were paying an extra $2944 per year if they did 8 subjects per year. Next year, fees for each subject will go up an extra $96. If they extend their degree by an extra semester, then, assuming they do three subjects, this would hit them with an extra $288 compared to if they’d finished ‘on time’. 
The student alleged that this was an unfair contract term under sections 23-28 of the Australian Consumer Law (ACL) – a term in a standard contract which can be varied unilaterally. This is unlikely, since, so far as I can tell, a contract is made for each subject and not for the course as a whole. Why each subject became individualised in this way is an interesting story with certain consequences, which will be gone into in a moment.

And in fact, MLS is quite clear on this issue in its statement on fees on the MLS website: 

“The indicative cost of the standard three year program for students commencing in 2016 is $119,442. This is an estimate only that is provided to assist you in making your decisions and is based on a 5% rise in fees per year, which is higher than the average rise in recent years. The University guarantees that fees will not increase by more than 10% for subjects in any year.” 

Nevertheless, the concerns raised by my colleague are important. ​
Picture
The Dean of the law school has at least a couple of times called the JD an “investment” (see here and here). But there is a problem with thinking of the JD as an investment. “Investments” are normally highly regulated. Chapter 6D of the Corporations Act, for instance, carefully regulates the manner in which corporations can fundraise. Prospective investors (unless they’re “sophisticated investors” (really rich people)), must be provided with disclosure statements. This is generally in the form of a “prospectus” (a full-disclosure document), though in some circumstances an offer of an “information statement” is enough.

“Investments” in education, on the other hand, are hardly regulated at all. Despite the fact that students may be spending in the hundreds of thousands of dollars, no information is provided regarding the risk of this so-called investment. The key piece of information which prospective students would need when considering whether to “invest” or not is the grad-jobs statistics. These are not available, however, though the Dean has stated that “there is an argument for law schools collecting and sharing information about job outcomes with students who are entering degrees.”

Further, risks are not adequately spelled out. Domestic students are often surprised to find out that they must come up with the $16k in cash which FEE-HELP won’t cover. A few weeks ago, for example, a student writing in De Minimis described their experience of having to get together $10,000. They did so by splitting it across two credit cards. Their advice to students considering the JD was first to speak to an accountant.

Further, the fact that fees are now paid unit by unit, rather than for the degree as a whole, means that all the risk of failure is put on the shoulders of students and none is put on the university. Let’s say a student makes it through 1.5 years of the JD but has a mental breakdown and can’t go on. They now owe more than $50,000 and have nothing to show for it. This is particularly harsh on international students who don’t have access to FEE-HELP. Such students have to pay their fees up front, mostly without financial help from their government. To do so they have often scrambled together money from their parents and extended family. If they don’t make it through the JD, they and their families incur a massive loss.

How universities came to charge per unit rather than for the whole degree began with the move towards university privatisation which was instituted by the Labor Government of the late 1980s. The higher education reforms of 1988 (the “Dawkins reforms”) allowed universities to charge fees for postgraduate courses. The concomitant decrease in government funding for universities caused Melbourne Law School, notably with some push back from faculty, to introduce a fee-paying program. Dean at the time Michael Crommelin has stated that this was “the only way we could acquire a little bit of space, a little bit of an opportunity to do anything else”.

In particular, the increasing size of law firms meant that lawyers were moving from more generalised practitioners to specialists, particularly regarding commercial matters. Specialisation created a demand for specialist courses, which was being provided for by independent conference and seminar organisers. “High fees” were being charged and good profits being made. Cheryl Saunders has stated that “it occurred to us that if they were putting pots of money there, they might be able to put slightly smaller pots in our direction, as long as the product was a high quality one”.

Note the commercial language thus introduced into education – it was becoming a “product”. Indeed, it was the Law School which pioneered at the University of Melbourne the use of consultants for market research. One of the first consultants engaged said that “the Law School lacks experience in being enterprising, market-responsive and competitive”. This soon changed – indeed, Cheryl Saunders helped the Law School win exemptions to the standard definitions of masters’ degrees and graduate diplomas from the university administration.

The move to the JD from the LLB marked the culmination of this move – rather than subjects for specialists being taught on the side, the entire course was now one big profit-making enterprise. But the course was now split into 24 units as if each unit was a ‘subject-on-the-side’, rather than a holistic part of a law degree. This was how financial risk was shifted onto the shoulders of students, and, in fact, onto the shoulders of the general public. Student debt is expected to balloon to $63 billion by 2019, up from $30 billion last year, with a fifth of all loans not expected to be repaid. It is the government which will foot the bill. Universities are privatising profits and socialising costs.  

The risks to students are only going to increase. The gap between the proportion of fees which can be covered by FEE-HELP and the total cost of the course is growing. Rather than increasing fees at the inflation rate and so in line with the increase in FEE-HELP made available, the university is increasing fees at double the inflation rate. This will only serve to punish those who don’t have access to easy cash-flow from their parents. I show this in the following graph, though unfortunately I did not have access to enough data to compare more than two years directly:
Picture
The Law School Dean invokes the “brand” of the University of Melbourne as what will mark MLS graduates out from other graduates in the job market. This brand she ties closely to how MLS is ranked in university rankings systems. Indeed, Melbourne’s ranking is often the piece of information students are advised to use to make their decision regarding their “investment”. As stated, however, by University of Adelaide Vice-Chancellor, Professor Warren Bebbington, “University rankings would have to be the worst consumer ratings in the retail market. In no other area are customers so badly served by consumer ratings as in the global student market”. “Next to buying a house”, he went on, “choosing a university education is, for most students, the largest financial commitment they will ever make. A degree costs more than a car, but if consumer advice for cars was this poor, there would be uproar”.
​

I should be clear that the fault is not all that of the university. As mentioned, the Labor government of the late 1980s began the privatisation of the university sector. Now, Australian government funding of universities is the second lowest in the OECD:
Picture
Governments across the OECD spent an average of 1.1 per cent of GDP on universities; Australia devoted just 0.7 per cent. Six countries – including Canada, at 1.6 per cent – spent at least double Australia’s proportion of national income. Finland, at 1.9 per cent, tops the list.

It is government, therefore, and especially the Labor party (remember those videos of Joe Hockey protesting in favour of free education?), which is to blame for the corporatisation of universities.

But corporatisation has been pushed from the inside as well. Corporatisation and an emphasis on profits tends to concentrate power in an elite at the top. We can see this in the huge salaries paid to university Vice-Chancellors: a headline from The Australian recently read, “Nine university vice-chancellors on more than $1m”. Melbourne’s Glyn Davis got $1.1 million last year. In June he also received, as a present from the University Council, more or less dictatorial powers as a result of University of Melbourne Statute changes.

The concentration of power and wealth at the top has meant that, rather than fighting for increased public funding, Australia’s premier tertiary education institutions, in their own words, have “consistently supported the proposal for the deregulation of higher education fees as the only long term sustainable solution”. Admirably, our own Glyn Davis at one time tried to argue against this and in favour of higher public funding. He even “once argued for higher taxes on people like me so more Australians could access a quality university education”. The reaction he got, however, was “hostile, personal and visceral”, he says, and so he now simply enjoys his money and power without complaint.

Perhaps this suggests that if we want to save our universities we will need to be a bit hostile and visceral (though “personal” may be too far).

What I hope to have shown in the above, at least in part, is that an education is not something which should be privatised and commercialised. An education is a public good; it makes us into responsible citizens; it gives us the tools of intellectual self-defence; it allows us to question; to embark upon intellectual journeys.

An education is not an “investment”. We cannot tell what a return on an education will be. Thinking of it as such will only prove to better serve the already well-off, shift risk onto students, and massively increase student stresses. It will make us into machines, there to mechanically do tasks without assessment of their merits and without question. That will be the only way for students to ensure a “return on investment”. In short, it will mean that we won’t be getting an education at all.

Education must be free. To paraphrase Charlie Chaplin, we are not machines; we are not cattle; we are human beings. And we deserve to be treated as such. Unfortunately, it seems we’ll have to be a bit hostile if we’re going to convince our university’s Supreme Leader(s) of this.

​Duncan Wallace is a third-year JD student and Chief Editor of De Minimis. This article is written in his personal capacity.
The rest of this week’s issue of De Minimis:
  • A First Year Lesson in Gender Equality
  • Melbourne Law School Fees Rising at Double the Rate of Inflation
  • The Matter of Marks
  • I'm Not Mad, I'm Just Disappointed
  • I'm Weary About the Ways of the World
​More articles like this:
  • University "Profitability" Trumps Freedom of Academic Expression Under Failed Policy
  • University of Melbourne Set to Show it is Willing to Risk Human Life on Earth in Order to Climb Rankings
Tim Sarder
13/10/2016 08:01:05 am

"It is government, therefore, and especially the Labor party (remember those videos of Joe Hockey protesting in favour of free education?), which is to blame for the corporatisation of universities."

I enjoyed the rest of your article, though I'm not sure why it's framed as a Labor attack. I won't dispute that fees came in under a Hawke government under the late 1980s - although, they had also been abolished under a Whitlam Labor government earlier. Do we really expect that fees wouldn't have come in under a successive Howard Liberal government if Labor hadn't brought them in - the same government that brought in WorkChoices? Why are you trying to hold up Joe Hockey as a folk hero? He was treasurer behind fee deregulation which was opposed by Labor.

It's not like we'd be getting a glorious era of accessible uni under the Liberal party -- and perhaps your point is that both major parties are disappointing and that reform is only accessible under the Greens/some other source, but that becomes muddled when Coalition policy isn't mentioned at all in your article and a young Hockey's advocacy is picked up on.

I think your point is strongest when you critique the corporate and private forces underpinning this; if a political argument is to be made alongside this, it needs more clarity.

Anon
13/10/2016 04:27:22 pm

It's an attack upon Labor because the socialists feel betrayed by the Labor party's 1980s realisation that a socialist economic model doesn't work. This was demonstrated by Whitlam's disastrous economic policy generally, but specifically his changes to eductation, i.e. "free university" vs the Commonwealth's scholarship scheme.

P.S. Workchoices was great unless you were a lazy, corrupt unionist.

Duncan
13/10/2016 10:00:06 pm

Lolol

Duncan
13/10/2016 09:59:29 pm

I wasn't attacking Labor specifically. I was nore pointing out that Labor and the Liberals have basically marginal differences. That was the point in invoking Hockey. What is key is getting both of them to move left. You can't really detach them policy-wise very far. I argue that point here: http://www.deminimis.com.au/home/unfair-budget-wont-even-fix-debt-problem

Education as a Many-Coloured Dreamcoat
13/10/2016 03:10:34 pm

Indeed, it is the myopic view of education as a mere economic investment that led to the Dawkins reforms and those since, with the demand-driven reforms a continuation of these. Education has value that cannot be quantified in the same way as any other financial investment, and it the sole focus on education as an investment that in the eyes of neoliberal governments, legitimises their approach, while in the eyes of people who think governments should do more to manage our society, is myopic.

On the economics side, much of the research and the data suggests investment in education by governments is worth it, not only for the populace, but for the tax revenue they derived from the growth. The more interest governments charge on students' HECS debts, the more profitable it is for government, but we must realise that nearly all investment on education is profitable for them (with the exception of those dodgy private courses that have started cropping up in the past few years!)

The main issue we see today though is the university degree bubble. Business is booming for education providers, both in the domestic markets and international markets. We are seeing an education export boom -- education being given to foreign students who not only want to learn from Australian unis, but have access to valuable Australian student visas...

The problem now is that those unis, increasingly privately funded by those international student fees and by full-fee paying postgrad students, are behaving like private corporations. It is obvious not only in their shifting business models, but also in the way they increasingly lobby governments - the Group of Eight unis are not dissimilar from mining lobbies or other big business lobbies.

Why this is it a problem that unis are behaving like private corps? Will they not be more productive, since they will respond to market forces so as to most efficiently allocate education services? Leaving aside education's value as a public good (that is, its provision has value to society at large that goes beyond its value to the individual who receives it), the education market does not work like other regular services markets.

This is for two reasons:
1) Students are not particularly price-sensitive to the cost of education. This is because they are able to access government debt for the most (if not all) of the cost of their studies. Whatever the degree costs, students really take it as a given, especially in the law market where Melbourne and Monash have such market power in Victoria.

2) Young consumers of education may not be making economic decisions that are as rational as they would in other markets. Universities deal in education, yes, but they also deal in dreams and in hopes for a better and more profitable future. Without proper information, education consumers are almost willing to pay anything when they are young and believing that they are destined to be the barristers and big guns of the future.

The result is that universities realise that they can open up more and more university places (as MLS has done in recent years with its JD), and charge greater and greater amounts (the JD is one of the most expensive degrees). This comes at the cost of the government (who holds the debt) and eventually students, and to the profit of the unis.

Universities are one of the pre-eminent modern rent-seeking corporations. Although they are not-for-profit statutory corporations, this does not stop them or their executives thinking and acting like those who work at private corporations. Pretty quickly, we have seen many university departments consumed by an obsession to meet budgets and make maximum profit. Admin and academic staff are cut, standards may be lowered, and more is spent on marketing. The business booms and unis make more profit, but that does not mean that there is greater freedom of inquiry or better quality research (those unquantifiable public interest goals that corporate executives don't bother pursuing).

But moreover, many students are left with greater student debt, and no promise of a job in a market where everyone is over-qualified (over-qualification is good for society, but bad for the employment market!!).

Do I believe in a return to Whitlam-era free education? No

However, I find it hard to justify the demand-driven system. Carolyn Evans points out that law school is still the best bet for a graduate job that pays well (http://www.afr.com/opinion/law-school-is-still-the-best-bet-for-a-graduate-job-that-pays-well-20160811-gqpz8n). And she may well be right.

The problem is that law students pay way more for their degrees than most other courses, because of the demand-driven system. Furthermore, the demand-driven system, aside from making the increasing number of MLS students compete harder against each other, effectively shuts out lesser law schools, whose graduates are struggling way harder than MLS's to get jobs. This is the way capitalism and competition wo


Comments are closed.
    Picture
  • Home
  • Podcast
  • Art
  • Get published!
  • ABOUT US
  • Archive
    • 2018
    • 2017
    • 2017 >
      • Semester 2 (Volume 12) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8 (election issue)
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
        • Issue 12
    • 2016 >
      • Semester 1 (Volume 9) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
        • Issue 12
      • Semester 2 (Volume 10) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8 (Election Issue)
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
        • Issue 12
        • Issue 13 (test)
    • 2015 >
      • Semester 1 (Volume 7) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
      • Semester 2 (Volume 8) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
    • 2014 >
      • Semester 1 (Volume 5) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
      • Semester 2 (Volume 6) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 12
    • 2013 >
      • Issue 1
      • Issue 2
      • Issue 3
      • Issue 4
      • Issue 5
      • Issue 6
    • 2012 >
      • Semester 1 (Volume 1) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
        • Issue 12
      • Semester 2 (Volume 2) >
        • Issue 1
        • Issue 2
        • Issue 3
        • Issue 4
        • Issue 5
        • Issue 6
        • Issue 7
        • Issue 8
        • Issue 9
        • Issue 10
        • Issue 11
        • Issue 12